Welcome! This site is intended for exchanging ideas on the topic of information technologies and their role in global politics. It is part of an online module in the M.A. International Relations Online Program at the Free University of Berlin.

The central theme of the module concerns the nature of global governance in a networked information environment.
We will begin by discussing neorealists and neoliberals' perspectives on the role of the media and information technologies in international relations. We will then define collective action and identify global efforts of such action in the form of transnational advocacy networks and the role of epistemic networks. We will conclude our module exploring the idea that the rise of global information flows has created a new system of governance, one that is parallel to the state system.

June 25, 2012

Resurrecting Durkheim


                In his work “De la division du travail social” first published in 1878, french sociologist Emile Durkheim has identified that the increase of work division and specialization of individuals has led the society to shift from what he describes as traditional society to modern society. In the traditional society, people are express solidarity with their peers because of the traditional, cultural, ideological and normative similitude (mechanical solidarity) between them whereas in modern society, solidarity would fall from the management of interdependence between individuals (organic solidarity)[i]. After having read Benkler and Nissembaum’s theory on commons-based peer production, I believe that the rising of such type of production can lead to a redefinition of Durkheim’s work and even suggest a shift back to some sort of mechanical solidarity.

                Benkler and Nissembaum have identified four different clusters of associations between virtues and characteristics of commons-based peer production.

Cluster I: Autonomy, Independence, Liberation
Cluster II: Creativity, Productivity, Industry
Cluster III: Benevolence, Charity, Generosity, Altruism
Cluster IV: Sociability, Camaraderie, Friendship, Cooperation, Civic Virtue

They also describe the peer production process to be exempt of hierarchical setting which would allow all protagonists to participate freely to the evolution of a project by sharing their thoughts and expertise.[ii]  Wikipedia would be an example of choice to depict the commons-based peer production. This web encyclopedia has gathered thousands of collaborators that were wailing to share their knowledge. In the Wikipedia setting, these subject matter experts do need recognition by their peers that their knowledge is actually valuable, and this fact points out the importance of the reference to society to exist. This apparent auto-regulation of peer production organizations does have a strong similitude with Adam Smith’s proposed model of the “invisible hand” to explain regulation of markets.[iii] But this time, replacing individualism by independence, altruism and cooperation (clusters I, III and IV). Durkheim’s definition of organic solidarity within the modern society also had a very strong link to interdependence between individuals. His vision of modern society is that individuals can only collaborate under contract where the need, extent of support and duration of collaboration is clearly defined.[iv]  Such model could not be valid for all the examples that are used by Benkler and Nissembaum (Wikipedia, SET, Clickworkers) as peer production is triggered from volunteer collaboration of individuals. The term collaboration is of paramount importance in this module as it encloses the ICT and individuals given that ICTs are now the medium through which collaboration is made possible partially because of the ease of assembly they offer.

                The collaboration of individuals in peer production is quite similar to what we have seen about TANs. In previous modules, we have seen the importance of TANs as possible alternative source of governance and how they can have a strong impact in their field of interest. TANs have brought together people with a same interest and a specific knowledge with regards to this interest. This networking of individuals is not made possible by interdependence but rather through the combination of similitude of interest. This type of network would therefore be more likely to meet Durkheim’s definition of traditional society and mechanical solidarity stated in the introduction.

                Durkheim’s research has led him to believe that the stronger the interdependence is, the more solidarity there will be between individuals. The objective itself is therefore less important as the individual is only asked to perform his attributed task in a flawless, timely manner. In commons-based peer production, the attention is put on the finality of the common effort as the individual does not receive any retribution besides the finalized common accomplishment. Solidarity in such settings takes its roots in the shared objective rather than in interdependence.

                It is clear that the interaction and collaboration between individuals involved in commons-based peer production does not go hand in hand with Durkheim’s vision of the modern society. ICTs have allowed the appearance of a form on knowledge altruism thus showing a potential ideology shift from “information is power” to “information is common good”.

                The most interesting thing about commons-based peer production is the opportunity that we have to see this evolve. I believe it is impossible for such organization to evolve without any sense of hierarchical structure. As peer production efforts get bigger and bigger, Anderson’s statement that “more is different” [v]will just make even more sense and steering in direction of an original common goal will be a great challenge. Shirky said: “whatever method helps coordinate group action will spread, no matter how inefficient they are, as long as they are better than nothing”.[vi]  Can this lack of efficiency become peer production’s sword of Damocles?
               

Ludovic Moulin


[i] Durkheim E., De la division du travail social, 1893, e-book numerized on 15.02.2002 by the University of Chicoutimi, accessible via http://classiques.uqac.ca/classiques/Durkheim_emile/division_du_travail/division_travail_1.pdf
[ii] Benkler Y., H. Nissenbaum, Commons-based Peer Production and Virtue, Journal of Political Philosophy, Vol. 14, No 4, 2006, pp 394-419
[iii] Rothschild E., Adam Smith and the Invisible Hand, The American Economic Review, 1994, pp 319-422
[iv] Durkheim E., De la division du travail social, 1893, e-book numerized on 15.02.2002 by the University of Chicoutimi, accessible via http://classiques.uqac.ca/classiques/Durkheim_emile/division_du_travail/division_travail_1.pdf
[v] Shirky C., Here Comes Everybody: The Power of Organizing without Organizations, New York, Penguin Press, pp 109-142
[vi] Shirky C., Here Comes Everybody: The Power of Organizing without Organizations, New York, Penguin Press, pp 109-142